Labels

Tuesday, March 24, 2015

Smoking Etiquette in Thailand

Though technically illegal, smoking in Thailand is very possible, and in some places downright common. Although everyone has a story about a friend of a friend who was caught with a joint, fined 100,000 dollars and thrown in jail for a couple days, there are even some bars with prominently displayed signs advertising that they can sell to you. It all depends on what areas you’re in.
Generally the best place to buy stuff is smoking bars. In Chiang Mai there is a bar right on the main drag called “THC rooftop bar” and outside a tuk-tuk driver sits waiting for customers. He will happily drive you around the corner to where his stash is, well, stashed and sell you a bag for 500-2000 baht and then return to his stoop and wait for his next client to come along. But be warned: smoking in Chiang Mai or Bangkok is someone sketchy, everyone except your hostel owner will tell you the best place is in your room. Smaller towns are a much safer bet.
In some places like Koh Tao it seems likely that the government knows about the specially designed “Rasta bars” where you can buy and smoke, and in some cases not only turns a blind eye but perhaps even profits from their existence. These places are generally a bit off the beaten path, and require some fortitude to get to. Places like the “Banana Bar” and the “View Point Bar” occupy real-estate at the end of long hilly dirt roads, and will sell you a bag or a joint, and allow you to smoke on their premises.
The View Point Bar in particular is listed as a national view point on the tourist map, and is also the highest point on the islands. There is even a 50 baht charge to enter the viewpoint, as in other government sponsored national parks. The woman at the gate who sold me my nondescript yellow ticket smiled as she informed me that my entrance fee was good for the whole day, and I was welcome to come back later and see the spectacular sunset for free. However, when leaving these areas the bartenders will often warn you to watch out for cops, and to stash your bag between you cock and balls for safe keeping.
With tourism as their number one industry, it seems like Thailand has realized that they can accrue the highest profit margins by catering to both smoking and non-smoking tourists simultaneously. Force the smokers to remote areas so they don’t bother more conservative family based tourism, and you can let people do their drugs and from time to time make some extra cash on the side by arresting stupid people who don’t respect this divide. Or perhaps it is a purely anarchal system that has arisen around the fringes of government surveillance to fill foreign and local demand. More research would be required to know for sure.
There are other areas that are basically reserved for hippies where you can smoke much more freely. 10 km outside of Pai is a joint called the Krazy Kitchen. Painted in rasta colors like most of these bars, this one is run by an elderly woman who will happily cook you a meal and smoke a joint with you. The product here is superior to most in Thailand, and it’s a chill place to wile the night away, In Pai you will receive no warning as you leave with your bag; people can be seen smoking in and around Pai.

In the Rock climber haven of Ton Sai smoking is perhaps even more common still. This is where you will see bars along the main strip openly advertising that they are selling bags, happy cookies, and even mushroom shakes. You will even find groups of locals sitting around smoking bamboo bongs and spliffs all day long, counting their money and cutting up bricks into bags for customers. How it came to be that some areas are completely devoid of police officers and full or hippies I cannot say (is it the dog wagging the tail or the tail wagging the dog), but it seems that there are unwritten rules in place to protect just about everyone involved in the industry. 

Resume

Resume
Alaitz Aritza

Education:
Bachelors of Arts and Science: Music, Culture and Cognition
Pitzer College, Claremont, CA
GPA: 3.65
Completed 12 week full semester summer program at Berkeley College of Music, 2012
Completed Advanced Spanish Program at La Catolica University, Quito, Ecuador,  2012
Completed Beginners Korean with Korea University through the Fulbright Program, 2014

Research Experience:
Pitzer College, Language and Music Cognition Lab 2013-2014
·        Prepared experiment stimuli
·        Drafted and edited IRB proposals for experiments
·        Ran participants through behavioral experiments
·        Applied, cleaned and recorded data from EEG equipment
·        Learned to use “presentation”, ”audacity”, “word”, “excel” and other computer programs
·        Prepared and design fliers advertising experiments
·        Person to person recruitment of participants
·        Prepared, manipulated and managed participant databases

Teaching Experience:
Fulbright Grantee 2014-2015
• Designing and implementing lesson plans to teach English as a Foreign Language to over 600 middle school students of varying abilities, as well as a week-long 20 hour winter English camp for 20 students.
Designing and Administering speaking performance tests for over 600 high school students
• Acting as an American cultural ambassador to the people of Jeju Island in South Korea
Discussion Group Leader with Pitzer College office of International Affairs 2013-2014
·        Led discussions in English for 6 hours a week with Japanese exchange students
·        Took students on weekly excursions to practice language in real life situations/facilitate cultural immersion
·        Tutored students with their class work
Intern/Teachers assistant at National Guitar Workshop, New Haven Conn. 2010-2011
·        Worked in a class room with various professional music teachers
·        Designed lesson plans for classes
·        Tutored individual students
·        Studied various pedagogies
·        Led ensembles, from teaching songs to students to performing with them on stage
Private Guitar/Voice Lessons 2006-present
·        Taught youth, peers, and adults for many years

Other Jobs:
Jr Councilor for Camp Fire USA, Salem MA 01970, 2006
General Labor for Marblehead Garden Center, Marblehead MA 01945, 2007-2008
Painter for the Salem Community Development Committee, Salem MA 01970 2009

References:
Professor/Advisor: Dan Segal, 909.607.3645, dsegal@pitzer.edu
Professor: David M. Tanenbaum, 909.621.8722, dtanenbaum@pomona.edu

Employer: Todd Sasaki, 909.621.8308, tsasaki@pitzer.edu

Monday, March 23, 2015

Tourism in Thailand

I hate it when people tell me Thailand is “too touristy (something I hear quite frequently). Not only because they fail to explain what they actually mean by that, or that the people who proclaim this are generally the same individuals who don’t speak more than a word or two of Thai, people who would be utterly lost without the tourist infrastructure they bemoan, but also because they are just plain wrong. Sure if you go to Kho San road in Bangkok, or the Pae Gate in Chiang Mai, or pretty much any of the small islands in the south, you will be surrounded by tourists. But if you take the time to walk ten minutes in any direction in one of these big cities you will quickly find yourself in another world, with locals gawking at you because they clearly are not used to seeing tourists.
After a few nights frequenting the backpacker and tourist joints in Chiang Mai some friends and I asked our hostel owner where she thought we should go out for the night. After ten minutes of walking we were a bit lost in an area completely devoid of English signs and English speakers. Fortunately with our five words of Thai we were directed towards the one guy in that neighborhood who spoke a bit of English, and he was able to set us back on course. When we arrived at the bar we were horribly out of place in our bro tanks and elephant pants, surrounded by well-dressed 20-35 year old Thai students and blue collar workers out for a night on the town.
Out of a hundred people packed into this bar we were the only tourists I was aware of. We saw two or three other white faces but they belonged not to tourists, but expats, most of whom spoke decent Thai and had been living in Chiang Mai for years. Thailand was full of amazing live music, but this bar was something special. Not only were they all wonderful musicians but they played with soul, making even the covers sound new with interesting and original arrangements. 
           But if you really want to get off the gringo trail and experience rural Thailand I recommend renting your own set of wheels. 200 baht or around 8 dollars a day will get you a semi-automatic 125 cc motorbike, and the countryside opens up to you in a new way. You could easily go weeks, months, or even years without seeing another tourist. I experiences this first hand during the 700 km epically beautiful Mae Hong Son loop leading me through national parks, water falls, hot springs, caves, and some of the best mountain roads and view points in the country, staying in rural villages that had never even heard the word guesthouse.
That being said Thailand does have their tourism game pretty figured out. Unless you are in a super rural area (and often even when you are) you can usually find someone who speaks a little English. You can show up somewhere at 11 pm and find some sort of cheap accommodations in most towns and cities after ten minutes of walking around and asking people, and it’s totally safe to do so. You can walk out of your hostel in Bangkok at 5 am and jump in a taxi 30 seconds later and be on your way to the airport. Every other shop and most guesthouses have tourist information and can sign you up for rafting, trekking or cooking classes, buy you bus or train tickets, and cook you an authentic Thai or western dinner.
So anyway I guess my point is Thailand is a big country with a lot of variety, and I don’t think that the fact that you can get a western meal in most big cities in addition to a plethora of authentic Thai food is necessarily a bad thing. If you want to stay in a five star hotel, you can, if you want to stay in a bungalow bamboo shack, you can, if you want to spend some time with a Thai family you can even sign up for a homestay. Thailand is a beautiful, diverse country, and like any other country it is what you make it. I think the people who proclaim Thailand to be too touristy never really took the time to explore it properly. So is Thailand to touristy, or are you too touristy?

Thirty Things I Learned Traveling Alone in Thailand

1. There's no such thing as traveling alone. Unless maybe you are going somewhere where there are no people.

2. If you try to be nice people notice they are usually nice to you. This is the best way to get what you want and life is more beautiful and enjoyable this way.

3. Travel light

4. No seriously, travel lighter. I brought a 40 liter pack that weighed 10 kg full for a 6 week trip and I would have been happier with way less stuff. A good rule of thumb, if you’re only planning on using it a couple of times, you probably don't need to bring it.

5. Almost anything can be a pillow. I have found sweatshirts to be the most comfortable, but an empty water bottle is not bad either. Books are so-so.

6. Speaking of books, most touristy places sell used books cheap. If you’re lucky you can even trade the book you just finished for a new one. Plus if you’re doing stuff every day you don't have as much time to read as you might think. Don't bring more than two books plus a guidebook.

7. Socks get smelly faster than any other article of clothing, but you can do laundry almost anywhere for a dollar or two. I should start hand washing things myself..

8. Never buy food at the airport. Walk five minutes around the corner and get the best meal of your life for a dollar from a street vendor.

9. Everything's an adventure if you have the right mindset and everything happens for a reason.

10. Most things take longer than expected, some things take less.

11. Traveling restores your faith in humanity and generosity.

12. It takes 2-3 days to get the hang of a place; it helps if there are rivers or mountains for orientation purposes.

13. You can just go to the airport and buy a ticket and get on a plane a couple hours later. It really works, and is often the cheapest way to travel. Especially recommended for flexible people who wouldn’t really mind spending an extra night in the amazing city they're already in (see rule 9)

14. Making friends is easy; it starts with a smile :)

15. There's good and bad in everything, what’s more important is what’s in you.

16. You can sleep anywhere if you’re tired enough, but you don't really need as much sleep as you think. Or as much anything as you think really. That being said listen to your body, it usually knows best.

17. When keeping a journal, it can be useful to write your pages in order rather than just opening the book and writing on the first blank page you find. This way you have a chronological record and it’s easier to find stuff if you want to add or change something. Adding dates can also be helpful.

18. It’s much better to write in a non-bumpy environment

19. Most of the good live music is up north, specifically: they play the same shitty mix of 90s/2000s pop music every night at most bars in Kho Tao but in Pai they have a different live musician every night.

20. Keeping a diary is good for memory and clarifying ones thoughts, smoking weed is good for pattern recognition and modification.

21. There are no wrong decisions, just different choices and options.

22. Always check out on time.

23. Sometimes, inexplicably, buses stop running at 5 o’clock.

24. Wandering around and asking prices is the best way to get a good deal on a hostel. Finding a good restaurant can be more challenging; you gotta trust your gut.

25. The coolest hippy bars on the islands are way off the beaten paths to avoid the cops. Somehow Tonsai and Pai seem to have gotten a free pass.

26. Always bring papers; they're the only smoking device that can’t get you arrested #allcigarettesaregoodfor

27. They don't pronounced the h that some fool added when Romanizing Thai script. Phang is pronounced pang (a sound as in restaurant)

28. Always keep a journal and try to write and read every day, or whenever possible

29. Having a hostel close to the loud bars is good if you want to party till they close and then stumble home, but not if you plan on going to bed early. One night it Kho Tao I fell also asleep to chirping crickets blending with Don Saco Duro thinking: at least I can’t smell the gasoline they are no doubt burning for the fire shows and flaming jump rope/limbo contests.

30. The places that no one has ever heard of were some of my favorites.

Smart Grids: A Technologically Powered Paradigm Shift

1.       What’s wrong with our paradigm?

During his year in office president Obama has adhered to a trend of exploring various alternative energy strategies while continuing to burn fossil fuels at an unprecedented rate and refusing to address the underlying issues of an economy designed around increasing consumption each year. Energy use is projected to nearly double globally (it is currently around 17.3 trillion KWH per year) in the next 20 years, increasing 2% each year in developed countries and 4% in the rest of the world. Generally when powerful interest propose that technological fixes will help save us from climate change it is wise to remain healthily skeptical, however one technological advancement lends itself particularly well to this paradigm shift away from growth that many countries have already picked up on.
 The necessity of this shift is made apparent by the graphs on this page; although GDP may increase, standard of living and general well- being do not. Median household income has also stagnated and inequality has increased as we have shifted from a production to speculation based economy. The dissatisfaction with neo-liberalist economic policies and the looming environmental crisis has led to a proliferation of alternative methods of measuring a nation’s progress, including GNH, GPI, genie coefficient and the index of sustainable economic welfare, among others. The subject of happiness related to money/consumption has been well studied by scientists across many disciplines, and it has been demonstrated that above a certain level, somewhere around the poverty level, more doesn’t serve to make people happier.
The culmination of these critiques of the traditional capitalist agenda can be seen in the leftward shift taking place in many Latin American countries in recent years (as well as movements like “Occupy” and more recently “Moral Mondays” in the US, riots in the EU, the Arab spring, etc.), with new constitutions being drafted around the ideal of well-being over that of increased annual consumption and productivity.
A smart grid would allow for an important shift in the operating rule of power supply, moving from a) utilities adjust output to meet demand, to b) homes and businesses adjust electrical use manually or automatically depending on the availability of power. Using electrical sensors/meters, basic information technology, and a wireless communications system, power lines can be made responsive to external factors. The implications of this transformation are quite profound, including various mechanisms for saving energy, avoiding waste, incorporating new green technologies, and perhaps most significantly, the decoupling of utilities profits from the amount of energy people consume.
This overhaul has already happened in California as well as many other developed nations, power companies in California no longer make more money based on how much energy their customers consume, but by how efficiently energy distribution is managed. This takes the abstract ideal of well-being and sustainability over increased GDP, wealth and consumption, and applys it to a concrete project that has been shown to be achievable and has had impressive results; while electricity consumption has increased dramatically throughout the rest of the US, it has remained steady in California. Today two Californians use less electricity than one Texan, meanwhile California still ranks among the top ten happiest states.



2.       What’s wrong with our power lines?

In 2000 the National academy of engineering declared our “vast network of electrification” the greatest engineering achievement of the 20th century, noting that it is only on the back of this system that most other things have been engineered. Yet power grids haven’t changed much in the last 100 years, working in a one way system with power stations delivering energy to a grid where it is distributed to factories, offices and homes.
Utilities still rely on consumers to tell them when the power has gone out, and then they must investigate why. Furthermore the customer has no idea how much energy he is using until he sees his bill.  Energy leaks and energy pilfering are also rampant, accounting to 10 percent of all energy in the US, up to 50 percent in some cities, and costing 150 billion a year. On top of that, these energy losses and outages generally require the use of diesel powered back-up generators.  Deregulation in the 90s encouraged companies to send energy over long distances, meaning some parts of the grid get congested, causing more wasted heat energy and blackout, costing an estimated 80 million annually.
Once a smart grid is in place, sensors on the transmission lines and smart meters on the customers premise to inform the utilities when something goes wrong. At worst the utilities can know what the problem is without sending someone to investigate, and at best smart switches can automatically route the power around the problem, sort of like how internet can redirect data packets. A data acquisition systems today provides information on the state of transmission lines every 4 seconds, which would be increased in a smart grid to 30 times per second, helping halt power surges before they develop into blackout. This will reduce the need for peaker power plants (which are generally dirtier than normal plants) and idling power plants, helping save money and the environment.
Conservative estimates say smart grid implementation will save the US 227 billion, 45 billion of which is estimated to be due to dynamic pricing, or changing the price in relation to demand. Private investment annually in the US towards smart grid technologies is around 200 million, and the most recent government stimuli had a 4 billion dollar chunk for smart grids. Morgan Stanley predicts the industry to grow from 20 billion today to 100 billion in 2030. The total projected cost of install in the US is around 50 billion, though relevantly we would need to throw around 450 billion into the conventional grid over the next ten years to meet expected demand increases.
3.       What else can smart grids do?
Three other promises from smart grid proponents includes mechanisms for decreasing consumption during peak hours, distributed generation, and increased feasibility of electrical cars. I will address each of these in this section.
Companies often cut back on consumption during peak hours, and now people can do the same both manually and automatically, saving an estimated between 20-30 percent during peak hours. A lower peak demand allows for reduced expensive backup capacity. Those advocating smart grids report that cutting just the top ten percent at peak hours could save consumers 100 million annually. Real time info on load and pricing will make this possible, and even allow for dynamic pricing.
Studies have shown people decrease energy use by 7-10 percent if they know their usage is more expensive when demand is high, which can be increased to 15 percent at peak times with added incentives. Reducing peak demand by just 5 percent would save 66 billion dollars in 20 years. Since the best smart grid technology promises to reduce peak demand by closer to 25 percent, it could save us closer to 325 billion in the same amount of time. Italy, a leader in smart grid technology, spent 300 billion to fit its country with 30 million smart meters and now saves around 500 million a year, an investment that will pay off in only 6 years.
Many green technologies have outputs that are a slave to the weather, as in they are distributed and intermittent. This wreaks havoc on a conventional grid built on a balance between supply and demand. With fossil fuels you can always burn something and get energy, and if you burn more stuff you get more energy, which can theoretically be done at any time.  The smart grid makes it easier for a utility to balance supply and demand during peak hours or extreme weather conditions, meaning they don’t need to construct as many new power stations and have the ability to incorporate renewable energies, even back yard solar panels or wind turbines.
It can also manage the charging of tens of thousands of electric cars at night when demand is low. If it’s a windy night cars can charge on the wind, or the plugged in cars can act as an energy storage system, holding energy in their batteries and then return it to the system when the wind drops utilizing a Vehicle to Grid (V2G) system. This again helps to balance the supply and demand of energy, saving energy and increasing efficiency.

4.       What does this technology consist of?

There are three strata technologies within the market which we hinted at in a previous section, but will discuss in more detail bellow.
Advanced Metering Infrastructure (AMI): This is basically a smart phone in your house, complete with chip, display, and connected to a communications network. It can monitor how much energy your using and when, and for what price. They will most likely be connect to one another through a wireless mesh network, where information travels from one meter to the next ultimately communicating with the utility and costumer simultaneously in real time.
The second stack technology is a database. The utility needs a way to manage all this data and set rates according to demand. And finally there exists a Home Area Network (HAN), comprised of thermostats and other systems for measuring energy that are connected to your AMI and other smart appliances. In this way your washing machine can wait to turn on until demand/price has dropped below a certain level, and other such innovations. People can set their devices to automatically turn off when demand is high, or utilities can manage demand at peak hours.

5.       Why don’t we have a smart grid yet?

There are several reasons. For one thing the technology is still improving, and is particularly lacking in terms of an efficient battery for energy storage. There are also worries that it could be vulnerable to cyber criminals. Issues of setting up standards for the network with compatible devices and devising a system to access historical billing information or real time metering data will be difficult, but it has already been done successfully in other countries. Importantly, old-fashioned power grids are a powerful (pardon the pun) special interest group, and there making money as is.
This connects with perhaps the most pertinent reason; smart grids are designed to reduce demand, and in a growth based economy businesses are incentivized away from this possibility. Efficient power distribution and a lower carbon footprint do not yet correlate with a utilities bottom line outside of California. So while power companies across the continent plan their future around added capacity and higher production California utilities are buying their customers cfls , installing smart meters, and replacing inefficient machines.
This all stems from a well-being over a productivist mindset; the idea the profits should flow towards that which is “social productive and ecologically beneficial”. This represents a realignment of interest towards a culture of efficiency rather than waste. I think smart grids are one of many avenues we should pursue in order to address “individual behavior, societal norms, institutional actions, and technological advances” with the goal of reduced consumption through appeal to human behavior and by drawing upon human creativity.



"Wiser Wires." The Economist. The Economist Newspaper, 8th Oct. 2009. Web. 11 Feb. 2014. http://www.economist.com/node/14586006
"Building the Smart Grid." The Economist. The Economist Newspaper, 4th June 2009. Web. 11 Feb. 2014. http://www.economist.com/node/13725843
Zehner, Ozzie. Green Illusions: The Dirty Secrets of Clean Energy and the Future of Environmentalism. Lincoln: University of Nebraska, 2012. Print.
“Mining for Smart Phones, the True Cost of Tin.” Friends of the Earth. http://www.foe.co.uk/sites/default/files/downloads/tin_mining.pdf
Ray F. Weiss et al., “Nitrogen Trifluoride in the Global Atmosphere” Geophysical Research Letters 35, no. L20821 (2008)

United Nations Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change; Richard Conniff ”The Greenhouse Gas that Knowbody Knew,” Yale Environment 360, November 13th 2008

The Future of Environmentalism

How do you get people to behave differently? Sometimes it’s as easy as changing the name of the game. In a variety of experiments pitting self-interest against cooperation, hearing the name of an economic game in passing had a profound impact on how people acted, though all the rules and instructions were the same. When playing the “Wall Street” game people act selfishly 60 percent of the time, when playing the “community” game this number immediately drops to 30 percent (Lieberman). So how do we change behavior? Change the context.
Saying that people are greedy in a society that rewards greedy behavior is like saying people consume a lot in a society that glorifies consumption, not only by individuals but as a political and economic ideology.  Lack of congruency between economic and environmental goals seems to me to be the number one issue preventing us from doing something about climate change, and developing that congruency may be all we really need to do. Remember the story of electricity use in California over the past 15 years (see my post on “Smart Grids”).
But an important question remains, what type of pressure is most suited to implementing this change for real Americans? Scientists tried placing messages on people’s doors asking them to turn off their A/C this summer and turn on their fans instead. The first message gave a monetary incentive, saying you could save 54 dollars a month. The second message said you could be a good citizen and help prevent blackouts. The third message said you could help save the environment. None of them had the slightest impact on people’s behavior.
So they tried a forth message. This one said that when surveyed, 77 percent of your neighbors say they turn off their A/C’s and turn on their fans. And people followed suite. Social pressure is an extremely powerful force influencing human behavior. The same thing that causes us all to accept the lives were living is the same force that can allow us to enact change. One startup company, Opower, has been taking advantage of this, partnering with energy companies in California to give people home energy reports comparing their energy use to that of their neighbors with targeted recommendations for improvement. This has helped save 2 terawatts of power in 2013 (Laskey).
But we mustn’t forget Jevons Paradox!!! Where is this saved money going? Because if it’s going towards increasing consumption then this is all for naught.  Taxes, caps, or regulations must be put in place to prevent growing consumption from smothering efficiency gains. This leads those studying the rebound effect to report that while increasing efficiency is important, “it is unlikely to be sufficient while rich countries continue to pursue high levels of economic growth” (Herring).
The same goes for alternative energy sources; “they are only as durable as the contexts we create for them” (Zehner). We know we don’t want to sacrifice our standard of living, and also that the vast majority of energy is used by corporations and the government (especially the military), so let’s talk about solutions to climate change that set achievable goals which are congruent with peoples self-interest, and improve people’s well-being.


Women’s Rights!!

Issues of women’s rights are seldom the first thing that comes to mind when thinking about how to address the problem of climate change.  While it is true that the entire population of the planet could fit in Texas, it is also true that we would need many earths for all those people to meet the consumption levels of the average American. Bartlett from the University of Colorado Boulder argues that modest growth rates in energy use, material consumption, or population lead to enormous escalation in short periods of time, citing man’s inability to understand exponential functions as “the greatest shortcoming of the human race” (Bartlett).
Taking Boulder, an area with fifteen times more land than people, as a case study, he shows that the growth rate of 2 percent suggested by the city council would cause the populace to overflow the valley in a single lifetime. 1 percent growth means a doubling of the population every 70 years, 2 percent means doubling every 35 years, and indeed the world population has doubled since 1970. But as I pointed out at the beginning of the section, modern capitalism is to blame for the energy crisis far more so than population; an American uses more energy in 2 days than a Tanzanian does in a year (Mckibben).
Although the US doesn’t have an official population policy, embedded in our taxes and legal system are policies favoring growth. We need more young people to pay social security for older people right? In reality children are expensive too. On average in the US they cost about 200,000 $ by their 18th birthday, and between 100-150,000 $ more if they want to go to college (Machlin and Rohde). Companies also spend less to replace the pay of caregiving parents and crime rates fall along with police and incarceration expenditures. With a focus on well-being of people over special interests, this shift will be difficult but not impossible; it’s already happening in places like Japan and Germany.
Many countries have managed to cut fertility rates in half by providing basic fertility information and contraceptives. Of course high fertility rates are a system of broader economic and gender inequities. Professor Hartmann argues that bringing population growth down is basically a matter of focusing on women’s rights and basic human needs (Hartmann). Also, population shifts will take generations to be noticeable, while communities will enjoy the benefits of prioritizing women’s rights immediately.
Here in the US we have the highest rate of teen pregnancy in the industrialized world. That’s 440,000 teen and preteen girls giving birth a year (Martin et al). American teens are also the least likely to use contraceptives due to stigmas on teenage sexual activity, high cost, and low availability (Guttmacher). The vast majority of these pregnancies, along with half of all pregnancies in the US are unplanned. The actual number is probably much larger, since people don’t always want to admit they didn’t plan their pregnancy. These unintended pregnancies have a direct medical cost of 5 billion a year (Trussell). Meanwhile the percentage of the total health aid budget allocated to women’s health in the US has dropped from 30 percent to 12 percent over the past decades (Zehner 188).
Statistician Murtaugh from Oregon State University claims that one American mother with two children creates the same carbon legacy of 136 Bangladeshi mothers with 337 kids. He explains that “An American child born today adds on average 10,407 tons of CO2 to the environment…6 times more than the mother’s entire lifetime emissions” (Murtaugh and Schlax). Lowering US teen birth rates alone to average European levels would save 30 billion KWH annually, while getting that much energy from rooftop solar would cost 500 billion a year (Zehner 219)! Adopting universal health care and changing attitudes towards teen sexuality may save us a lot of money and energy in the long run, while promoting greater utilitarian happiness.

Packaging and Advertising!!

Many of the top paid psychologists in the world work for ad agencies, preying on consumer’s insecurities and vulnerabilities to sell more products. 3-5 year olds consistently choose McDonalds french-fries and branded carrots over the generic versions, even more markedly if they watch a lot of television (Kraemer). The money spent advertising different kinds of foods to kid’s looks like an inverted food pyramid (55 percent soda, candy and snacks, 26 percent fast food, 15 percent cereal, 3 percent dairy, and <1 percent fruits and vegetables) (Zehner 229). Labs used advanced eye tracking and brain monitoring technology to study how kids respond to different labels and ads, meanwhile marketing personnel working for these agencies describe a double life, manipulating children in the name of profit by day and shielding their own kids from the same ads at night (Koval, 186).
While almost 90 percent of American teenage girls name shopping as their favorite pastime, studies have shown that advertising exacerbates anxiety, depression, low self-esteem, and other psychosomatic issues (Suter). Conversely the more materialistic we are the more at risk we are for these diseases (Koval, 167). Perhaps related to this, Americans now spend more time in traffic, work longer hours and have less vacation, but have bigger houses and more stuff in them, than at any point in history. Scientists are starting to call this the work-spend cycle, and economists are calling the psychological inculcation as disease they call affluenza, or “a growing and unhealthy preoccupation with material things” (Hamilton and Denniss, 90).
Maybe we just shouldn’t be advertising to children under twelve, we wouldn’t be the first country to institute such a ban. In fact, today American cartoons are the only English language children’s programs in the world that still take breaks for advertising (Dalmeny). This is not surprising since the APA has linked advertising to children with “misperceptions of healthy nutrition habits, parental conflict, materialistic values, and more positive attitudes towards alcohol and tobacco” and strongly recommends restricting ads to children (Kunkel et al.). The FTC attempted it in the 70s but was blocked by powerful corporate lobbies.
On another front, junk mail in the US accounts for a hundred million trees each year that must be grown, cut, hauled, processed, rolled, printed, and shipped to homes across America to be placed directly in the garbage (Novak). This requires the equivalent energy to of eleven coal fire power plants running continuously (Ford). Where does it end up? Perhaps in the ten million square mile island of debris congealed in the Pacific Ocean.
A full one third of plastic consumption goes to packaging (Zehner, 252). Meanwhile a third of our waste is packaging (US EPA, 84). More packaging not only uses more and wastes more upfront, but also creates a downward spiral, greater shipping energy, greater store/refrigeration size, harder to get back to your home without the use of a car, more energy to dispose of waste, etc.  In some European countries companies have to pay upfront for the eventual recycling and disposal of packaging.  Smarter packaging would save money, benefit everyone other than advertisers, and has been successfully implemented elsewhere.
Most people are against this waste. In many industrialized countries you can put a sticker on your mail box to discontinue junk mail. Introducing such a policy in the US would have a greater energy impact than all existing and planned solar power combined (Ford). Thwarting consumer culture starts with dismantling advertising, but ends with creating attractive social and educational alternatives. For example, in Germany instead of kids hanging out in shopping malls they go to Jugendhaus, nonprofit assemblages of open-work cafes, discos, restaurants, farms, etc. organized, operated and staffed by youth.
As I discussed in my previous essay, it is time to ditch the GDP, whose creator reported to congress in 1934 “the welfare of a nation can scarcely be inferred from a measure of national income” (Kuznets, quoted in Zehner, 254). As long as we remain in this productivist mindset, creating these simple and necessary changes will be far more difficult than it ought to be. The majority of Americans already embrace this alternate reality where social benefits are valued over increases in materialistic wealth; 70 percent say they would be happier with lower salaries if it meant living closer to their friends (Benjamin).

Bicycles!!

Promoting bicycle infrastructure would provide urban mobility, bring health benefits, and enhance public welfare, all for far less than we pay to support the growth and maintenance of automotive infrastructure. Many global cities have done this and now enjoy cleaner, healthier, quieter and safer neighborhoods. In America however, biking to school has fallen 75 percent in the last 30 years while child obesity rates have tripled (Hubsmith).
When I studied in Quito and it took well over an hr to get to school each day, sitting in a dirty, dangerous bus. Every Sunday they closed one of the main roads in the city to cars, and reserved it for bikes and pedestrians. I could easily bike to school in half the time. Perhaps more importantly, it was one of the most enjoyable and liberating experiences of my life. I wasn’t allowed to take the bike during the week because the roads are extremely unsafe for bikers; a few years back a Pitzer student was in an accident.
Over a quarter of the trips Americans make are under a mile, 40 percent are less than two miles, but 90 percent of these are made by car (Pucher and Renne #1). Less than one percent of trips are made by bikes. In chilly Canada people are twice as likely to bike, and in some European countries people are 20 times as likely (Pucher and Renne #2). Steve Miller from the Harvard public school of health explains that few people have time to go exercise; we need to incorporate physical activity into our daily routine. He estimates that by biking two miles each way on a daily commute we could prevent ten pounds of fat accumulation a year, not to mention the numerous other physical and psychological benefits associated with exercise (Miller). Another benefit would be increased mobility for youth and seniors; in Germany 50 percent of senior trips are made biking or walking (Pucher and Renne #2).
We all know our physical, political, economic, and social world has been constructed around the automobile, making other forms of transportation unpleasant, inconvenient and unsafe. While bicycle trips have increased as accidents decrease in Germany, bicycling in the US remains dangerous in most areas and use is declining, especially among children. Students at Bridgewater-Raritan high school students raised money for a bike rack only to have the plan rejected by the principal, citing safety concerns. Island Park elementary school principal vetoed a proposed bike path claiming a biker had been hit recently while walking his bike crossing a street (Zehner 281-282).
One group who deals with these issues is Safe Routes to Schools. In a pilot program they have seen a 64 percent increase in walking to school, 114 percent increase in biking and a 91 percent increase in carpooling. Despite this they receive only .2 percent of the US department of transportation’s safety budget. In California, for every dollar that gets spent on Safe Routes, 7 are spent on solar cells (Zehner 283). You can guess which is more effective in combating climate change and reducing CO2 emissions. Meanwhile students hold bake sales to get bike racks while the solar industry receives billions in public funding.
Some US cities have already started to prioritize biking. Davis California has built 50 miles of bike lanes since 1966 and people have begun to commute to work and school with the same frequency as Europeans. Steamboat spring Colorado is another example, where studded tires and an extra layer of clothing allow people of all ages to access the city’s schools, college, library,  grocery stores, post office, and hot springs. Another inspiring example comes from a school in Boulder which has started a program called “Boltage”. Students receive radio frequency identification tags to track their trips, calories burned and gas saved, all while competing to earn prizes. Expanding programs like this could help cut into many forms of public spending, including 76 billion dollars a year due to inactivity, 40 billion due to vehicular air pollution stemming from the first few minutes of a drive when the engine is cold and empower youth to use their bikes as a form of transportation for other activities as well (Zehner 294-296).

Stop Subsidizing Energy and Cars!!

Let’s think for a second about some of the ways we subsidize some of the greatest producers of climate change with our tax dollars…
We invest in the military for security right? We invest in the military for energy security. For each tax dollar you give to the government, 41 cents goes to the military. Less than 7 cents goes to education, environment, energy, and science combined (National Priorities Project: Interactive tax chart). We can’t afford safe bike routes around schools and universal health care because we have a limited concept of energy security constrained by vested corporate interests. In reality, these humanitarian projects would do a lot more towards securing our future than a new flight of bombers or tanks. This video gives a humorous take on the travesty of wasted military spending. http://thedailyshow.cc.com/videos/5i4rmi/tanks--but-no-tanks
When money flows from tax payer dollars into the military industrial complex it has negative repercussions for our environment in two discreet ways. First of that money that could be flowing towards something socially responsible or ecologically beneficial is instead going to produce energy intensive weapons, the vast majority of which are entirely unnecessary in terms of our defense. Secondly, this money is being spent to procure even more energy resources. This means taxes that go to support the military are massively subsidizing the cost of our energy. Think the war in Iraq. What do we do with cheap energy? We consume more of it than we would otherwise. Exploitative labor practices abroad also lead to an artificially low price of goods, which again results in increased consumption.
We spend hundreds of billions of dollars in tax payer money each year to subsidize cars. We’re talking about pollution, building and maintaining roads (since 2000 we’ve build enough new lane miles to circle the earth 4 times! See video bellow), medical costs associated with accidents, traffic police, military protection of oil fields and supply lines, etc. This is not to mention parking, in which tax dollars go to reserve and maintain some of the most valuable and potentially useful real-estate in the country, in case we may at one point wish to store our cars there. These subsidies are unjustly paid for by all taxpayers, whether or not they drive a vehicle. One group of activists seeks to challenge this misuse of public space by turning parking spaces into PARKing spaces one day a year, complete with trees, picnic tables, and art exhibits (Parkingday.org).
Americans spend an average of 45 hrs a month in their cars, and one workweek a year in heavy traffic, costing some 3 billion gallons of fuel and 80 billion dollars in lost time (Pisarski). Since 1925 we have been aware that increasing street size or adding more streets does not help decrease traffic. However removing streets can sometimes do just that. Braess’s paradox explained this phenomenon some 40 years later, showing that new roads often decrease rather than increase the efficiency of a network. The inverse is exemplified by traffic restriction of Broadway st in New York City, which led to overall traffic improvement. http://www.pbs.org/america-revealed/teachers/lesson-plan/3/
To maintain our quality of life we may sometimes need a car, but we shouldn’t have to own one to reap the benefits of this mode of transportation. Car sharing could save the average user between 2 and 5 thousand dollars annually, while allowing you to take a truck one day and a sports car the next (Pisarski). Since you have to pay upfront when you use the vehicle rather than in some distant future, drivers are more likely to carpool or use alternatives, and have been shown to spur a 50 percent increase in public transit, a 25 percent increase in walking, and a 10 percent increase in cycling (Zehner 290). The vehicles can then be stored at neighborhood hubs with better access to alternative fueling options. This would simultaneously allow us to take back roadside parking lanes for bicycles and wider sidewalks with trees.
Zoning laws force planners to reserve space for garages in new cities and suburbs, even if they will never be used. This would make most downtown areas illegal to build today, and causes low density areas that are difficult to navigate by foot or bicycle. Turning some of these garages into small efficiency rentals would allow teachers, students, service employees, social workers, and many others to live in the city, closer to where they work and with easier access to all their basic necessities without the use of a car. A truck bringing tightly packed with food bringing it to neighborhood outlets is far more efficient than many hybrids driving with a few grocery bags each (Zehner 297). While the suburb sprawl we live in is comfortably familiar, when asked to choose between pictures of walkable communities and suburban sprawl American’s chose the former (Leinberger).  

Food and shelter!!

In addition to supporting population growth, our taxation policies also support greater consumption. For example, public school funding is linked to housing prices, if you want to go to a good public school you have to move into a bigger house in a fancier neighborhood. In addition to a luxury taxed levied on the highest levels of consumption affecting only the wealthiest 1 percent of the population, an energy tax could be implemented to make the price of goods reflect the entire cost of their energy side effects. A tax on raw energy sales would filter down to ensure a consumption tax appropriately adjusted to an items carbon footprint.  Identifying the almonds at the store with the lowest energy footprint could be as easy as checking the price tag (Zehner 319).
For every day Americans don’t eat meat they save 100 megatons in CO2 emissions. The UN recently determined that livestock production leads to more human linked greenhouse gas emissions than all of the planets cars, trucks, buses, trains, and airplanes as well as the rest of the world’s transportation infrastructure combined. It also accounts for more land alteration than our entire suburban sprawl and more water pollution than all domestic water and sewage combined. Meanwhile vegetarians enjoy lower obesity, blood pressure, cholesterol as well as risk of heart disease and stroke, the greatest cause of death the US. Meanwhile, 40 percent of all food is wasted, accounting for 300 million barrels of oil annually (Thieme).
Another good example of our culture of waste is our grass lawns, which take up more land than all our wheat, corn, and soy production combined.  They also cost about 40 billion dollars a year, require 35 million pounds of pesticide a year, and accounts for full third of the domestic water supply (Pouyat et al.). The purpose of the lawn is of course to be cared for, and to show off for your neighbors. Few people spend any time actually using their lawns as anything more than a display piece, glorifying the natural landscape it is in fact smothering.

Government and Corporations!!

We all know our government has a lot of problems. For one thing our monetary system requires economic growth. Banks make loans that have interest, so the overall value of goods and services must rise at least in tandem. Inflation must increase, the economy must grow. Decoupling an energy companies profits from its production is a small step, but other groups are investigating a more comprehensive monetary reform to address these issues (New Economics Foundation).
One important first step would be to enact voting reforms. Abandoning the Electoral College and moving to a national popular vote would be an important first step, image if Gore won the presidency. Another would be to allow voters to pick their 1st 2nd and 3rd choices, along with campaign finance regulations. Energy expert from Harvard university Max Bazerman explains…”money corrupts the potential for an intelligent decision making process on energy policy. Well-funded and well organized special interest groups have disproportionate influence on specific policies…by simply donating enough money to the right politicians they effectively turn congress away from making energy wise decisions”(Bazerman quoted in Zehner 329).

Buildings and Trees!!

Building efficiency standards are a big deal. In some areas buildings consume 80 percent of all electricity. Could efficiency standards do the same for buildings as they did for refrigerators? Unfortunately LEED ratings give points for flashy green wash items rather than for actual energy impacts, which is mostly determined by factors like passive solar, air movement systems, and of course trees, which can reduce the carbon footprint of a building by up to a third (Butry).
They also make oxygen, consume carbon dioxide, fix nitrogen, distil water, accrue solar energy as fuel, make complex sugars, create microclimates, change color with the seasons, self-replicate, etc. According to the New York City tree census, the price tag for a mature oak is about 90,000 $. However the cities trees also save 28 million in air conditioning, 5 million in air filtration, 36 million in storm water absorbtion and .75 million in carbon dioxide absorption. For every dollar NYC spends on trees they get back 5.60 in benefits (New York City Department of Parks and Recreation).
The European Example:
Europeans typically work 35 hr weeks with 8 weeks paid vacation a year. They have smaller houses and consume less than Americans in almost every category, but consistently rank happier in psychological studies. Doctors in Europe stress preventative medicine can be seen quickly and even make house calls, but the per capita medical spending is less (Zehner 239).
The Dutch, for example, use less than half our energy, have less poverty and air pollution, lower, debt, extremely clean tap water, lower obesity rate, and a higher standard of living. Could it be they’re not happier in spite of their lower energy use but because of it? The future of how to implement carbon taxes and environmental regulations has been documented in European history books (Zehner 301).
Germany imposed an ecological tax reform including higher taxes on energy intensive products like gasoline and electricity. This not only increased rail use, carpooling, and other more efficient means of transportation, it also reportedly led to the creation of 60,000 new jobs, while offsetting 7 million tons of CO2 by 2002. A comprehensive energy tax could be an important step for the US, but it would also require international agreements to prevent polluters from shifting to places without such regulations (Zehner 321).  

Conclusion

Although I hope that one day all our power comes from “renewable” sources, creating more energy will not solve our energy crisis, or as some are calling it, our consumptions crisis. In a country like ours with problems in efficiency, suburban sprawl, growing population, and focus on material consumption, alternative forms of energy production will do little to address the problem; in fact they may even do more harm than good, leading us to the false premise that we can continue living in such an energy intensive manner.
Here are some goals that Ozzie Zehner points out to help us reimagine the social conditions of energy use,
1.       The US consumes less energy per capita than the average OECD nation.
2.       Lower wealth gap between rich and poor, universal health care, low murder rates, teen pregnancy, incarceration, etc.
3.       Cars and buildings should be more efficient than the average OECD nation
4.       Top fiftieth percentile for walkable and bikable communities
5.       A growing energy tax to stifle rebound effects
It goes without saying that all forms of energy production have their environmental and social impacts. Should environmentalists be involved in any time of energy production while these important issues discussed above remain unaddressed? Or should they serve to as watchdogs of power production companies regardless of their method. Solar panels may be sexier that women’s rights, consumer culture, walkable neighborhoods, zoning, military waste, zoning, health disparities, citizen governments, economic reform etc but they won’t do anything but produce power, which can only help us given the right context. Ultimately clean energy is less energy.
Zehner claims building up our alternative energy stockpile in our current social, political, and economic climate is akin to trying to build a bigger sand castle to withstand the rising tide. The problem is that many of us are asking the wrong question. The question is not whether “American society has the technology to construct an alternative energy nation, but do we have a society capable of being powered by alternative energy” (Zehner 342).



Bibliography
Albert A. Bartlett, The Essential Exponential! The Future of our Planet, Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press, 2004
Alex Laskey, “How Behavioral Science Can Lower your Energy Bill” https://www.ted.com/talks/alex_laskey_how_behavioral_science_can_lower_your_energy_bill
Bill Mckibben, Waste Not Want, Mother Jones, June 2009, 50 http://www.motherjones.com/environment/2009/05/waste-not-want-not
Butry, D. T. The value of shade: Estimating the effect of urban trees on summertime electricity use. Energy and Buildings, 662-668.
Christopher Leinberger, Retrofitting real estate finance: Alternatives to the Nineteen Standard Product Types. http://connection.ebscohost.com/c/articles/18584100/retrofitting-real-estate-finance-alternatives-nineteen-standard-product-types
Dalmeny, K. Television advertising and children: lessons from policy development.Public Health Nutrition
Daniel J. Benjamin, Do People Seek to Maximize Happiness? Evidence from new Surveys. http://www.nber.org/papers/w16489
Ford, Junk Mail’s Impact on Global Warming; Energy Information Administration. http://donotmail.org/downloads/ClimateReport.pdf
Guttmacher Institute, “teenages’ sexual and reproductive health: developed countries” http://www.guttmacher.org/pubs/us_teens.pdf
Hamilton, C., & Denniss, R. (2005). Affluenza: when too much is never enough. Crows Nest, NSW: Allen & Unwin.
Hartmann, B. (1987). Reproductive rights and wrongs: the global politics of population control and contraceptive choice. New York: Harper & Row.
Herring, H. (2009). Energy efficiency and sustainable consumption: the rebound effect. Basingstoke [England: Palgrave Macmillan.
Deborah Hubsmith, safe routes to school national
partnership, http://saferoutespartnership.org/about/centers-disease-control-and-prevention-presents-2012-%E2%80%9Cgame-changer-award%E2%80%9D-safe-routes-school-0#overlay-context=blog/cdc-provides-game-changer-award-safe-routes-school-national-partnership
James Trussell, “The Cost of Unintended Pregnancies in the US” http://www.contraceptionjournal.org/article/S0010-7824(06)00447-1/abstract
Joyce A. Martin et al, Births: Final Data for 2006 in National Vital Statistics Report http://www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/nvsr/nvsr57/nvsr57_07.pdf
Kraemer, H. C. Effects Of Fast Food Branding On Young Children's Taste Preferences.Archives of Pediatrics and Adolescent Medicine, 792-797
Kunkel et al, Report of the APA task force on advertising to children. https://www.apa.org/pi/families/resources/advertising-children.pdf
Laura Novak, “For Profit Crusade Against Junk Mail,” New York Times, September 6th 2007
Matt Lieberman, talk at Pomona College, March 24 2014, The Social Brain and its Superpowers
Murtaugh and Schlax, Reproduction and the Carbon Legacy of Individuals http://blog.oregonlive.com/environment_impact/2009/07/carbon%20legacy.pdf
New York City Department of Parks and Recreation, NYC street tree census 2007 http://www.fs.fed.us/psw/programs/cufr/products/2/psw_cufr687_NYC_MFRA.pdf
Pisarski ,The connected car, economists technology quarterly, June 2009, 18 and Commuting in America 3, http://onlinepubs.trb.org/onlinepubs/nchrp/ciaiii.pdf
Pouyat, Richard V., Ian D. Yesilonis, and Nancy E. Golubiewski,A Comparison Of Soil Organic Carbon Stocks Between Residential Turf Grass And Native Soil. Urban Ecosystems, , 45-62.
Pucher and Renne #1, Socioeconomics of Urban Travel: Evidence from the 2001 NHTS,  http://fmip.ornl.gov/2001/articles/socioeconomicsOfUrbanTravel.pdf
Pucher and Renne #2,Promoting Safe Walking and Cycling to Improve Public Health: Lessons From The Netherlands and Germany, http://policy.rutgers.edu/faculty/pucher/ajphfromjacobsen.pdf
Schor, J. (2004). Born to buy: the commercialized child and the new consumer culture. New York: Scribner.
Steven R. Machlin and Frederick Rohde, Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality, Health care expenditures for uncomplicated pregnancies. http://meps.ahrq.gov/data_stats/Pub_ProdResults_Details.jsp?pt=Research+Findings&opt=2&id=1058
Steve Miller, why health care should be a transportation issue. http://blog.livablestreets.info/?p=137
Suter, K. (2003). Global order and global disorder globalization and the nation-state. Westport, Conn.: Praeger.
Thieme, M. (Director). (2008). Meat the truth : Alalena Production.
 US EPA, municipal and solid waste 2008, http://www.epa.gov/waste/nonhaz/municipal/pubs/msw2008rpt.pdf

Zehner, O. (2012). Green illusions: the dirty secrets of clean energy and the future of environmentalism. Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press.